- capital becomes increasingly difficult to accumulate due to persistent erosion through theft and violence and disincentives for its accumulation, resulting in lower productivity
- industry and thrift are discouraged, resulting in lower output and investment
- the division of labor contracts as ethical breaches cause individual actors to find it increasingly difficult to trade or otherwise interact in a constructive, mutually beneficial manner, reducing overall productivity as actors seek greater self-sufficiency
- greater resources are devoted to the maintenance of capital and wealth, which is at greater risk of loss
Wednesday, August 12, 2009
Capitalism and Ethics II: Ethics as Capital
Introduction
In this essay, I will attempt to present the case that ethics may be considered as a form of capital and look at some of the insights such a consideration will provide. I will briefly describe the principles of economic growth and wealth creation, how ethics fits into this model, and look at how consideration of ethics as capital can help explain some high-profile economic phenomena. I will conclude with a summary and what this line of reasoning reveals about the likely course of future events.
The Wealth of Men and Nations
The accumulation of wealth occurs through a rather simple mechanism. Wealth is the product of human industry, or effort; without industry, there can be no wealth. Other things being equal, greater industry results in greater wealth.
That which multiplies human effort also multiplies the generation of wealth. We call those factors which increase the output of human effort capital, and so the accumulation of wealth over time is achieved through the accumulation of capital. Capital can materially consist of many things, including physical tools, education, and improvements in infrastructure. The erosion of capital or a reduction in human industry necessarily leads to an erosion of wealth.
Capital itself is accumulated through thrift, which is the curtailment of consumption for the purpose of saving or investment. Investment is the acquisition of capital through the purchase of a capital good and increases the productive capabilities of some economic actor or actors. Saving also results in the acquisition of capital by other economic actors, as it leaves resources available in the marketplace which may be devoted to other purposes. This activity can benefit the saver through the collection of interest.
Higher levels of thrift result in both lower interest rates as savers compete with one another to attract interest-payers, i.e., investors and entrepreneurs, and in lower prices of resources in the marketplace as greater quantities of resources are left unconsumed. Thrift is a measure of the availability of surplus resources and its action results in the allocation of resources away from consumer goods and towards the acquisition of capital goods, which will allow greater future production and consumption.
The degree of the presence of these three qualities, industry, capital, and thrift, broadly define the propensity for the accumulation of wealth.
The Emergence of Trade and the Division of Labor
Finite beings like humans have limited capabilities, and the increasing demands of more complex and more productive capital structures demand that they focus time and attention on activities that are ever more limited in scope. This tendency limits the capacity for individuals to satisfy their own varied consumer wants and needs through their own individual efforts; specialization necessarily comes at the expense of self-sufficiency. Trade with other economic actors becomes increasingly necessary, as individuals focus effort to increase productivity in specialized fields and exchange the fruits of their labor with other highly productive, highly specialized economic actors.
A more highly capitalized, wealthy society is therefore necessarily a society in which individuals become dependent on trade with one another for the satisfaction of their needs. Over time, the accumulation of wealth, and therefore capital, results in a restructuring of economic and social arrangements as participating actors become increasingly specialized in their productive activities. The specialization of productive activities, restructuring of social and economic arrangements, and the trade that emerges in response to the accumulation of capital is called the division of labor. A high division of labor is typically associated with a wealthy society.
Maintenance of Wealth and Capital
Both accumulated wealth and capital require maintenance. Parts wear out, materials rust and decay, and machinery grows old and obsolete as new technologies are developed. Even our own minds become feeble as we age and forget the lessons of our education and experience past. The forces of chaos and erosion are perpetually at work.
As an economic actor increases his capital and wealth holdings, greater and greater portions of output will have to be devoted to maintenance of present holdings, reducing that portion available for further capital and wealth acquisitions. The greater the property holdings, the greater these responsibilities become until the point is reached that no greater holdings can be managed sustainably. An economy with a high division of labor will have higher maintenance costs relative to a lower division of labor economy.
Resources and Technology
Two facets of economic development which are often erroneously cited as the principle source of wealth differentials are resources and technology.
Resources which are themselves the products of wealth-generating economic activities, for example, foodstuffs and other finished goods, can hardly be considered the principle causes of said wealth; therefore, in considering resources as a principle cause of wealth, we will limit the discussion to natural resources, those naturally occurring resources which are extracted from the natural world and are not primarily a result of human labor, though some labor may be expended in gathering them together or putting them to use.
The tendency to identify natural resources as a principle contributor to wealth probably arises from the observation of highly visible material prosperity in certain locations such as the oil-rich Middle East. It certainly is true that there is a good deal of observable wealth that could reasonably be expected to have resulted purely from the extraction of natural resources.
However, it is not true that an absence of natural resources will result in an inability to accumulate wealth, as there are almost always ways of achieving high productivity even in the absence of material resources. For one thing, it is often the case that one resource may be substituted for another, such as the substitution of coal or natural gas as a source of energy for oil. Desired resources may also be obtained through simple trade, or even rendered entirely unnecessary by technological development. The widespread availability of wireless phones has rendered interconnecting communication lines, and the materials needed to produce them, virtually unnecessary for this application in a very short time, freeing up these materials for other uses.
The spectacular economic success of resource poor Japan and South Korea is a testament to the ability of economies to develop despite shortcomings in natural resources. These nations import natural resources from more resource rich areas, convert them to final products, and then sell these value-added goods profitably. In effect, they are trading their own labor in exchange for natural resources. Conversely, resource rich Africa and Russia, which have lagged economically behind the West for centuries, are examples of resource rich areas which have historically lagged behind other economies in their degree of development, tragically so in the case of Africa.
Examples such as Saudi Arabia tend to be transiently wealthy. Saudi Arabia has had oil deposits for centuries, yet only became wealthy in the last 60 years or so when demand for oil from foreign countries with developed economies began to increase rapidly. It was not able to use its oil resources to enhance wealth on its own, and will probably return to relative impoverishment when the West no longer demands as much oil or when the oil runs out. Both facts point not to oil as the source of wealth in this particular case, but to the developed foreign economies which have devised ways of mobilizing this resource to satisfy consumer demand. Saudi Arabia prospers by happenstance of geography and on the shoulders of the industry, thrift, and capital of others.
Technology is the practical application of knowledge to achieve specific ends. Technologically more advanced economies are capable of greater output as their applied capital is more effective at increasing a given input of human labor. However, this statement itself should reveal the falsehood of the assertion that technology is a principle cause of wealth accumulation: technology is itself a form of capital. Technology is one of the results of the accumulation of wealth; highly capitalized and wealthy societies are able to fund the development of better technologies, so again, the result of a well-developed economy can hardly be named a principle cause. Further, most technologies are readily transferable from one population to another, and what is available to one should in principle be available to others in due time. Computers were not invented in China, but they are produced in vast quantities by China today.
So, technology and natural resources are both important, but are not in-and-of-themselves the primary, fundamental causes of wealth generation.
Ethics as Capital
Previously, we saw that proper ethics are critical to the development of a capitalist economy. We saw that in the absence of adherence to an ethical code:
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment